December 20, 2010
Saito, Osamu and Tokihiko Settsu (2006) Money, credit and Smithian growth in Tokugawa Japan. Hitotsubashi University. Institute of Economic Research. Discussion Paper #139.

In Osaka, Japan’s commercial capital, under the Tokugawa, rich merchants began to add to their functions that of lender to the mighty overlords (daymo) who needed to transform the production of their domain in bullion in order to cover their expenses in Edo and the taxes due to the Shogun (p.2). At the time, the country was segmented in small local capital market and no security was traded over the whole country. Despite those limitations, the rural industries did grow over the period, yet for that they had to have access to some fundings. Where did this capital come from? (p.3)
This wholesaler system arose in replacement of an inexistent banking sector (p.4). However this organization favored greatly the Osaka merchant who managed to impose de facto their service as a necessary precondition to any industrial or agricultural endeavor (p.5). But at that time, local merchants took on Osaka’s oligopoly.
To develop the production and trade of a wealth of proto-industrial products, they started delivering themselves those products to Edo, thus by-passing the Osaka intermediaries. Local lords backed these initiatives, for instance by issuing bank notes (hansatsu) to remedy to the dramatic shortages of money (p.9). However often successful, these initiatives led to a quick segmentation of the Japanese capital market and each of these small areas suffered from high interest rates (more than 18%), while at the same time interest rates in Osaka kept following (p.10).
A system, close to the earlier one arose after the Meiji Revolution, but this time with several commercial cities as the center of the operations instead of Osaka alone (p.13).
3 Comments |
Asia, Early Modern, Economic History, reading notes | Tagged: Edo, finance, finance and growth, financing industry, hansatsu, Japan, Osaka, proto-industry, rural industries, Tokugawa, wholesalers |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
August 2, 2009
Clingingsmith, David and Williamson, Jeffrey G. (2008) “Deindstrialization in 18th and 19th century India: Mughal decline, climate shocks and British industrial ascent”, Exploration in Economic History, 45/3, 209-234.



Between 1700 and 1900, India went from being an industrial powerhouse to forgotten backwater. Why didn’t India manage to retain its edge and how did Britain overtake the giant? Read the rest of this entry »
2 Comments |
Asia, Early Modern, Economic History, reading notes | Tagged: British Empire, colonial, colonies, colony, deindustrialization, East India Company, India, industrial revolution, industry, Mughal, proto-industry, South Asia, textile |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
March 2, 2009
Çizakca, Murat (1980) “Price History and the Bursa Silk Industry: A Study in Ottoman Industrial Decline, 1550-1650”, The Journal of Economic History, 40/3, 533-550.



Introduction
“The Ottoman Empire, which covered most of Eastern Europe and the Near East in the sixteenth century, did not escape the worldwide inflation that is generally known as the ‘price revolution’” (p.533). The price series of this article are based on the estimates made by the kadi of the Bursa court in numerous inheritance cases (p.535). Raw silk prices jumped from 73.8 akçes on average in 1550-70 to 290.4 on average in 1620-40, a 293% increase (±8.5% yearly inflation; p.536). Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Economic History | Tagged: 1500s, 1600s, Bursa, competition, desindustrialization, industry, inflation, Ottoman, Price revolution, proto-industry, rise of the West, silk, textile |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
February 22, 2009
Epstein Stephen R. (2000) “The origins of protoindustry, c.1300-c.1550”, in idem Freedom and Growth. The rise of states and markets in Europe, 1300-1750, New York/London: Routledge/LSE, p.106-146.



Introduction
“The growth of rural and small town textile manufactures for regional and supra-regional markets was among the most significant features of the late medieval economy” (p.106). It is usually assumed that this phenomenon arose due to the diseconomies caused by the inflexibility of the urban craft guilds, using the available underemployed rural workforce, and to respond to the increased popular demand for consumer goods following the shift in terms of trade between capital and labour which followed the Black Death. Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Economic History, Europe, Middle Ages, reading notes | Tagged: 1300s, 1400s, 1500s, cities, cluster, economic geography, industry, institutions, Italy, location theory, Lombardy, proto-industry, Sicily, state-making, textile, Tuscany |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
February 4, 2009
Davis, Robert C. (1991) Shipbuilders of the Venetian Arsenal. Workers and workplace in the preindustrial city, Baltimore/Londres: John Hopkins University Press, 270p.



While medieval and Renaissance Venice have fascinated historians, less has been written about the city in the 17th century. This book is about the community of the workers of the Arsenal (aka the arsenalotti) from 1620 to 1670.
The Arsenal was created in the 1100s and grew steadily until the 1300s. By that time, it had became a production plant and warehouse reaching a dimension unique in Europe. Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe, reading notes | Tagged: 1600s, Arsenal, class struggle, galleys, industry, Italy, proto-industry, ships, shipyard, Venice, work, workers |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
February 4, 2009
Thompson, J.K.J. (1983) “Variations in industrial structure in pre-industrial Languedoc”, in Berg, Maxine, Hudson, Pat, and Sonenscher, Michael, Manufacture in town and country before the factory, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 61-91.



Introduction
Languedoc hosted France’s (and potentially Europe’s) largest pre-modern concentration of textile textile production (p.61). Yet it does not fit in F. Mendel’s proto-industrialisation model: it was mostly a urban phenomenon, which dated back from the Middle Ages and it did not lead to a regional Industrial Revolution after 1800 (p.62). Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe | Tagged: 1500s, 1600s, 1700s, France, industry, Languedoc, proto-industry, textile, urban economy |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
July 20, 2008
De Sousa Fernando (2005) “The silk industry in Trás-os-Montes during the Ancient Regime”, e-Journal of Portuguese History, 3/2, 14 p.


This article is available on line.
Introduction
Trás-os-Montes is located in the North East of Portugal, it is a land-locked region close to the Spanish border. The silk industry started there in the 15th century but silkworms had been reared in the region since the 1200s. Although a significant part of the activity was located in Bragança, lesser towns and the countryside also enjoyed a share of it (Vinhais, Freixo de Espadaà Cinta, Chacim) (1). Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe, reading notes | Tagged: 1500s, 1600s, 1700s, 1800s, industry, Portugal, production, proto-industry, textile |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
July 6, 2008
Arnoux Mathieu (2001) “Innovation technique et genèse de l’entreprise. Quelques réflexions à partir de l’exemple de la métallurgie européenne (XIIIe-XVIe siècles)”, Histoire, économie & société, 20/4, 447-454.


This article is available online!
Introduction
Metallurgy and the related industries have been significant players in the economic development of 12th- and 13th-century Europe. All over the period metal consumption increased significantly. The producers met the demand by finding ways of increasing their productivity. Hydraulic energy was used to hammer larger pieces of iron and steel and then to ventilate furnaces (448). The new process was further developed in Belgium (the so-called Walloon process) and spread all over Europe in 1450-1550. Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe, Middle Ages, reading notes | Tagged: 1200s, 1300s, 1400s, 1500s, industry, innovation, metallurgy, proto-industry |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
January 27, 2008
Britnell Richard H. (2001) “Specialization of work in England, 1100-1300”, Economic History Review, 54/1, 1-16.



Introduction
The 12th and 13th centuries experienced growing population. The more people, the more likely it is that some will become specialized in an activity where they enjoy a comparative advantage (see Adam Smith). Persson has estimated that this led to a 0.1 to 0.25 yearly increase of productivity per caput in England over two centuries (i.e. between 22 and 62% for the whole period). But to what extend the period’s productivity gains are attributable to specialization? Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Economic History, Europe, Middle Ages, reading notes | Tagged: 1100s, 1200s, 1300s, city, development, England, growth, guilds, labour, proto-industry, Smithian growth, specialisation, urban economy |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
December 9, 2007
SMITH Thomas C. (1973) “Pre-Modern Economic Growth: Japan and the West”, Past and Present, 60, 127-160.


Definition of “pre-modern growth”
The income per capita advantage enjoyed before the Industrial Revolution (IR) by subsequently first-world developed countries (Europe, its offshoots and Japan). Meaning that income level before IR would be a proxy of incomes level in 1973. Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Asia, Early Modern, Economic History, reading notes | Tagged: 1600s, 1700s, Japan, proto-industry, Tokugawa |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
November 4, 2007
Reynard Pierre Claude (2000) “Manufacturing quality in the pre-industrial age: finding value in diversity”, Economic History Review, 53/3, 493-516.


Introduction
Recent historiography has insisted on the dynamism of West European manufactures at the eve of the Industrial Revolution. This was due to the multiplication of workshops, and – to a lesser extend – to new techniques. The author focuses his attention on a third cause: acceleration and intensification of existing processes. He uses the hand-made paper industry as an example of this ‘speeding-up’ process (493). Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe, reading notes | Tagged: 1700s, France, industry, management, production, proto-industry |
Permalink
Posted by Ben
October 28, 2007
Mendels Franklin F. (1972) “Proto-industrialization: The First Phase of the Industrialization Process”, The Journal of Economic History, 32/1, The Tasks of Economic History, 241-261.


Definition of the concept
Proto-industrialisation: “the rapid growth of traditionally organised but market-oriented, principally rural industry. It was also accompanied by changes in the spatial organisation of the rural economy” (241). The pattern of European agricultural production, created a massive but short-lived, seasonal demand for labour during the harvest. Journeymen were underemployed during the year, they were an available workforce for the labour-intensive textile industry which needed a lot of workers as its productivity had hardly increased since the 12th century (242). Read the rest of this entry »
Leave a Comment » |
Early Modern, Economic History, Europe, reading notes | Tagged: 1700s, consumer behaviour, consumption, demography, industrious revolution, industry, labour, Labour market, Netherlands, proto-industry, work |
Permalink
Posted by Ben